future-themes-systems-951037310-1500x410
Future Themes | Systems

Central bank digital currencies: Debunking five common myths

Santiago Millán, CFA, Macro Strategist
Ranjit Ramachandran, CFA, Equity Portfolio Manager
2022-04-30
Archived info
Archived pieces remain available on the site. Please consider the publish date while reading these older pieces.

The views expressed are those of the author at the time of writing. Other teams may hold different views and make different investment decisions. The value of your investment may become worth more or less than at the time of original investment. While any third-party data used is considered reliable, its accuracy is not guaranteed. For professional, institutional, or accredited investors only.

Central bank digital currencies (CBDCs) will, in our view, almost certainly be issued and widely used in the future. In five years, we believe there will be roughly a dozen CBDCs and, in 10 years, we think nearly every country will have them. After all, 85% of central banks currently have a CBDC project.1

CBDCs will likely never be a large part of the overall money supply, however, which mainly consists of financial system deposits (rather than those at a central bank). In our view, they will coexist with both cash and existing forms of electronic money, rather than replacing them. We believe the demand for paper money will ensure that it will not be eliminated in most countries for decades or even longer.

In this short paper, we discuss how disruptive CBDCs are likely to be and dispel some commonly held CBDC myths.

CBDCs’ potential for disruption

In theory, CBDCs could be significantly disruptive, as they could compete with bank deposits, facilitate capital flight, or have substantially different characteristics. For example, they could automatically pay negative interest rates or even have an expiration date.

In practice, however, we do not believe CBDCs will be as disruptive as commonly advertised. We think policymakers are conscious that if central banks compete with the nonsovereign financial sector, it will result in disintermediation. Thus, in our view, policymakers will ensure CBDCs are, in most relevant ways, a complement instead of a substitute for private-sector money and financial services.

Notably, we believe fintech will thrive in a CBDC world, and CBDCs will become important inputs that can be leveraged for all sorts of financial products for individuals, firms, and governments alike. They could enable much more precise and targeted macro policy, for example, by providing stimulus and subsidies directly to specific groups of people, such as by age group, geography, or occupation status.

Debunking common central bank digital currencies misconceptions

As market interest in CBDCs grows, we believe they have caused some consistent misconceptions. Here, we look to dispel five of the most frequently discussed CBDC myths.

Misconception #1: CBDCs are new

In the past, it was common for central banks to accept retail deposits. For example, the Bank of Spain did until 1962. In addition, central bank digital currency (in retail form) existed as early as the 1990s, when Finland introduced the Avant Card. However, central bank retail deposits were abolished so that central banks would not compete with the rest of the financial system. And the Avant Card failed because its network of users was too small. So, what is new is not CBDCs, but the fact that they can now quickly establish themselves in modern digital networks, where buyers and sellers can access them effortlessly and ubiquitously.

Misconception #2: CBDCs will massively disrupt the banking system

Central banks no longer allow retail deposits because doing so disrupted the outside banking system and the overall financial system. For this reason, we believe central banks will only allow functionality to the extent that it does not disintermediate the private sector or other outside players. With that said, CBDCs will likely place significant competitive pressure on areas where governments see the industry’s products as a public good, such as payments.

Misconception #3: CBDCs will make private payments systems redundant

As noted above, we think policymakers will be careful not to cause too much disruption with the introduction of CBDCs. After all, their main role is to preserve stability and protect the financial sector itself. In our view, most payments in the economy, whether in China or in the West, will remain digital and electronic, but will involve private money such as bank deposits or Alipay, rather than CBDCs.

Misconception #4: CBDCs will be extremely functional and complex

It is exciting to think about the possibilities for CBDCs to transform macro policy. And it may be scary to think about the possibilities for governments to track every single transaction a person makes. But it is important to remember that with every new functionality for a CBDC, there is also a new cost. In our view, this means central banks will be very careful to make sure the public will accept the currency. We believe this means, for example, ensuring that below a certain denomination all transactions will be anonymous, just as with cash. Notably, however, in economies where most transactions are digital already, users have very little anonymity when it comes to their purchasing behavior.

Misconception #5: CBDCs will upend the existing dollar reserve system

We believe it is unlikely that CBDCs in and of themselves will disrupt the existing international financial system. However, we do think they could be one of several factors (including economic and geopolitical fragmentation and the rise of unorthodox monetary policy in developed countries) that together could precipitate the biggest changes in the international financial architecture since the end of World War II.

Recent developments in central bank digital currencies

China’s CBDC project, which started in 2014 with a 10-year implementation time frame, has been in testing phases for more than a year. It is available in increasing numbers of cities and also internationally, via agreements with the authorities of Thailand and the United Arab Emirates (UAE). The currency will likely remain in trial mode for at least several years, until policymakers are satisfied with the currency’s functionality or if other countries’ currency debuts put increased urgency on the plan.2

Recently, the Biden administration in the US, along with the US Federal Reserve, appear to be taking the topic more seriously.3 Notable developments elsewhere in the world include Sweden’s e-krona project and Switzerland’s Project Helvetia.4

Bottom line: CBDC investment implications

In our view, CBDCs will be positive for financial system development and will be a very useful tool for fintech. In addition, we think the ease of transactions could push liquidity into scarce assets (e.g., gold, crypto). However, we do not believe they will be a significant threat to traditional financial institutions or systems, though they could be sources of competitive pressure in some areas, such as payments.

Critically, we think CBDCs will increase in relevance and prevalence in the years to come and the above misconceptions are likely to be dispelled along the way.


1International Monetary Fund, 2020. | 2Sources: SCMP, April 2021. CGTN, December 2020. Wall Street Journal, April 2021. | 3Bloomberg, April 2021. | 4Reuters, December 2020.

Authored by
millan-santiago
Santiago Millán, CFA
Macro Strategist
Hong Kong
ranjit-ramachandran-300x300
Ranjit Ramachandran, CFA
Equity Portfolio Manager
Boston

RECOMMENDED FOR YOU